Sunday, August 28, 2011

LECTURE 15. RECESSION & RECOVERY


For a deeper understanding of the collapse and the problems of recovery than we can provide, read this and this. This lecture consists of a combination of direct quotations, paraphrasing, and slight additions to the work of Scott Fullwiler, Randall Wray, and others at the "New Economic Perspectives" blog.

RECESSION

Now that we have the accounting model (Lecture 3), we can understand the recession. The three balances (Private, Government, and Export surpluses) must balance to zero. This implies that it is impossible to change one of the balances without having a change in at least one other. Just remember that, with little change in net exports, a government budget deficit is a surplus for the private sector and a government budget surplus is a deficit for the private sector. The facts are as follows: Since the advent of offshore tax deferrals signed into law in 1976 by President Gerald Ford, the US manufacturing industry has been hollowed out to a shell of its heyday. A corporation would be foolish to operate a domestic plant when taxes and labor costs are less elsewhere. The result is the deterioration of the middle class and three decades of consumer borrowing. Eventually the private sector became a net borrower. Borrowing by the private sector allowed both the Clinton boom and the 2000s boom and caused the government budget deficit to fall (and to actually move into a large surplus during the Clinton years). The expansion before the global financial collapse (GFC) had been led (mostly) by the 2000s housing boom, during which households borrowed (and spent) on an unprecedented scale. In the Clinton boom, about half the deficit spending was by firms; however in the 2000s boom it was entirely the household sector that spent more than its income. In 2005, tax revenues were growing much faster than both government spending and GDP growth. Thus, the private sector was forced further into debt. Such fiscal tightening (called fiscal drag) often is followed by a downturn — and the downturn that accompanied the GFC was no exception. The GFC was triggered by private sector debt but the collapse was due to deregulation and non-regulation of the finance, insurance, and rating industries. When the GFC came, the federal budget deficits increased, mostly automatically. While government consumption expenditures remained flat over the downturn , the rate of growth of tax revenues dropped sharply from a 5% growth rate to a 10% negative growth rate over just three quarters (from Q 4 of 2007 to Q 2 of 2008), reaching another low of -15% in Q1 of 2009. Transfer payments (unemployment and other benefits) grew at an average rate of 10% since 2007. Decreasing taxes coupled with increased transfer payments automatically pushed the federal budget into a larger deficit, notwithstanding the flat consumption expenditures. As the economy slowed, the federal budget automatically went into a deficit, putting a floor under private demand. With countercyclical spending and cyclical tax reduction, the government’s budget acts as a powerful automatic stabilizer: deficits increase sharply in a downturn. This helps the private sector. The automatic stabilizer – more than the bailouts and stimulus—are the main reasons why the economy did not go into a free fall as it had in the Great Depression of the 1930s. The private sector had more money to spend.

RECOVERY

Since the crash, the household sector has retrenched, and saving remains high. The result is low demand, slow growth, and a rapidly growing budget deficit.

The Government Sector

The national conversation presumes that government budget deficits are discretionary (i.e, subject to control by policy). If only the government were to try hard enough, it could slash its deficit. But shrinking the government’s deficit will require either that the private sector spend more relative to its income or that the US net export deficit fall sharply. But households are still heavily indebted and indeed more and more homeowners are falling “underwater”—so the likelihood that they will drop saving back down to the 2-3% range we saw in the 2000s seems unlikely. At the aggregate level, government spending (mostly) determines private sector income. A sector can spend more than its income, but that means another spends less. While we can take government spending as more-or-less discretionary, government tax revenue depends largely on economic performance. Government cannot decide what its tax revenue will be because we apply a tax rate to variables like income and wealth that are outside government control. And that means the budgetary outcome — whether surplus, balanced, or deficit — is not really discretionary.

The Private Sector

We could hope for a domestic private business sector boom but that is unlikely. With high unemployment, depressed domestic demand, and stagnant sales, investment by firms is not going to grow that much. Investment-led booms are really residential housing investment booms and there is little chance that we will see a housing construction boom in the near future.

The Foreign Sector

The final possibility is the foreign sector. Imports are running around 18% of GDP (rebounding sharply since the GFC) and exports are at 14% of GDP—so exports are up, but imports are climbing a bit faster (this difference is mostly due to oil). While it is true that the US net export balance has become less negative in recent months, much more movement will be required to actually get to positive territory (more than 3% of GDP of adjustment would be required). Note that the last time we actually had a positive net export balance was in the Bush (41) recession —two decades ago. Exports are largely outside control of the US. (US efforts to increase exports will almost certainly lead to responses abroad). It is true that economic outcomes in the US can influence exports — but impacts of policy on exports are weak. On the other hand, US imports depend largely on US income; if the US tried to reduce imports this would almost certainly lead to responses by trading partners that are pursuing trade-led growth. Imports are largely pro- cyclical, too. Again, our net export outcome—whether deficit, surplus, or balanced — is also largely non-discretionary. Remember, to reduce the government sector deficit from the current 9% or so of GDP toward balance will require some combination of a private sector movement toward deficit and a net export movement toward surplus amounting to a total of 9% points of GDP. That is huge. The problem is that actually trying to balance the budget through spending cuts or tax increases could reduce economic growth. Lower economic growth could conceivably reduce our net export deficit—by making Americans too poor to buy imports, by lowering US wages and prices to make our exports more competitive, and by reducing the value of the dollar. Note that all of those are painful adjustments for Americans. And it might not work, because it requires the US to slow without that affecting the global economy—if it also slows, US exports will not increase.

The Way Out

What is discretionary? Domestic spending — by households, firms, and government—is largely discretionary. And spending largely determines our income. It makes most sense to promote spending that will utilize domestic resources close to capacity, and then let sectorial balances fall where they may. As we will argue further, the best domestic policy is to pursue full employment and price stability—not to target arbitrary government deficit or debt limits, which are mostly non-discretionary, anyway.

The Alternative to Full Employment

The current unemployment rate is about 9%. With a poulation of 300 million and a population growth rate reaching toward 1%, we need to add 115,000 jobs/month to avoid a higher unemployment rate. With our present rate of GDP growth, the following is the expected result: To lower the unemployment rate to 8% within 2 years, we would need to add 191,000 jobs/month. To lower the unemployment rate to 7% within 3 years, we would need to add 208,000 jobs/month. To lower the unemployment rate to 6% within 4 years, we would need to add 216,000 jobs/month. Over the last 50 years, we have added an average of 125,000 jobs/month and have rarely exceeded 200,000 jobs/month, even with a strong manufacturing industry and housing booms and without Asian and Brazilian competition. Think about the future of children without a policy of full employment.

Proceed to: Lecture 16. EVALUATION OF THE STIMULUS


Thanks for your interest. Marvin Sussman, retired engineer If you don’t like the world as it is, change it this way!:
1. Depress the Shift Key, sweep the cursor over the following URL, click, copy, and paste it on email to friends, and ask them to do the same: Keynesian Economics 101 The ONLY way out of this mess Free lectures on-line: KeynesForum.blogspot.com
2. To print and distribute single-sheet “invitations” to this site, click here and ask your friends to do the same.
3. To donate toward advertising this website, click the yellow “Donate” button below. You will be asked for your PayPal account password. If you don't have a PayPal account, you will need a credit card.
And ask your friends to do the same.
Copyright © 2011 Marvin Sussman All rights reserved.

No comments:

Post a Comment